SURPLUSES & DEFICITS ARE HOTLY DEBATED, BUT DONTFORGET THE CURRENCY
Much has been made of Britain's trade deficit, which is the amount by
which our imports of goods and services exceed our exports. The
same phenomenon is evident in many other strong economies,
including the USA.
It is a situation that protectionists like Donald Trump feel the need to
"do something about", such as recourse to tariffs in order to redress
the gap - but these bring down retaliatory counter-measures in their
wake. And so the combat proceeds.
But protectionists overlook the fact that one of the main reasons for
exporting is to be able to import, and it is clearly mistaken to think of
exports as "good" and imports as " bad", especially as we cannot
control the conduct of our trading partners.
Every trading nation must honour its debts
While every trading nation has to honour its debts to those with
whom it transacts business, it is obvious that at any single point in
time there will be an imbalance between imports and exports. Since
it is impossible for every trading nation to have a permanent trading
surplus, to wish for it is simply wishing to inflict the demon deficit on
someone else, which takes us no further.
A country's "current account deficit" differs from its "trade deficit"
The latter is, of course, the largest component of the current account
deficit, which also includes inward investments, capital flows and
international borrowing.
A country's current account deficit is therefore its accumulated
foreign debt, which in time must be repaid. If the deficit country is
creditworthy the foreign holders of that debt will not be concerned
about the risk of non-repayment, especially when those foreign
holders are aware that the deficit country is using its borrowings to
finance the creation and acquisition of capital assets that will work
towards reducing the the deficit.
Therefore, despite the panic stirred up about having a deficit, trading
with foreigners is in essence no different from trading with locals
always just as beneficial from an aggregate economic point of
and view. is
Paying for our imports
When a British importer buys German goods he must pay for them in
euros. For that purpose he (or his agent) will acquire euros from a
German bank and, after settling the bill the German exporter (or his
bank) will now be a holder of British pounds. What will he do with
them?
He can use them to buy British goods, or even UK treasury bonds, or
he can exchange them for a preferred currency - but if, instead, he
does nothing with those pounds and merely sits on them indefinitely
he will, just like the retailer who never cashes your cheque, be
handing the importer a free gift!
The only legitimate concern for those whose trading partners use
a different currency relates to the relative "strength" of the
currencies concerned.
Protecting the currencies
No exporter will accept payment for his goods in a currency that he
does not trust because of its volatile, unstable purchasing power, and
consequently will not be trusted by his other trading partners either.
At a time when the US dollar was respected for having all the virtues
of a "reserve" currency, traders in exporting countries with weaker
currencies all over the world would insist that payments for their
produce, raw materials and manufactures should be denominated in
dollars.
That is changing now, of course, because (i) the Federal Reserve (the
USA's central bank) continues its policy of encouraging ballooning
credit in its variety of forms, and (ii) other nations, notably China and
Russia, are inclining towards stricter monetary discipline, even to the
point of building up their gold reserves at a rate that threatens the
worth of all the unanchored "fiat money" that other central banks are
so furiously churning out, relative to the yuan and the rouble.
Protecting our currencies is therefore the real issue underlying much
of the debate about post-Brexit trading relations. The most important
favour that EU trading entities can seek from their own governments
and from the European Central Bank is to desist from destroying the
value of their currency.
This is now a universal problem - with central banks embarked on a
veritable race to the bottom! By their actions they appear to be hell-
bent on destroying the yen, the euro, the dollar and the pound. They
claim, of course, that their actions were responsible for saving the
world's monetary systems from implosion after the 2008/2009
collapse, but the truth is the very reverse
Such is the prevailing ignorance that those actions, now staging a
repeat performance, are merely setting the scene for another crisis
inevitably more extreme in its scope and reach. Repeats of economic
disasters can be averted only by tackling their causes - not by
fiddling with symptoms and after-the-event results
And a brief footnote
Central banks are notorious interventionists in every aspect of
monetary and fiscal policy. They even believe that having a weak
currency may be good for certain exporters by making their goods
and services cheaper for overseas customers, but that advantage is
counterbalanced by the disadvantage to non-exporting businesses
that require goods and services from overseas.
Furthermore, the deliberate action by a central bank to favour
exporters by weakening the currency causes prices in general to rise
over time, and this in turn eats into the exporters' margins - the very
people this policy is intended to help!
And so it continues until the next round of currency debasement.
Again and again. In this foolhardy seesaw there can be no winners.